Reference: | Bank, J.S. (1993), Two-sided uncertainty in the monopoly agenda setter model, Journal of Public Economics , 50, 429-444.
Bishop, J.A., Formby, J.P., and Smith, W. (1991), Incomplete information, income redistribution and risk averse median behavior, Public Choice, 68(1-3), 41-55.
Blume, A. (1995), Communication-proof equilibria in cheap talk games, Journal Of Economic Theory, 65, 359-382.
Calvert, R. (1985), The value of biased information: a rational choice model of political advice, Journal of Politics, 47, 530-555.
Conlon, J. R. (1993), Can government talk cheap ? communication ,announcements and cheap talk, Southern Economic Journal, 60, 418-429.
Crawford, V. and Sobel, J. (1982), Strategic information transmission, Econometrica, 50(6), 1431-1454.
Eichenberger, R. and Serna, A. (1996), Random errors, dirty information, and politics, Public Choice, 86(1-2), 137-156.
Farrel, J. and Gibbons, R. (1989), Cheap talk with two audiences, The American Economic Review, 79(5), 1214-1223.
Feddersen, T. and Pesendorfer, W. (1998), Convicting the innocent: the inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting, American Political Science Review, 92(1), 23-35.
Feddersen, T. and Pesendorfer, W. (1996), The swing voter’s curse, American Economic Review, 86, 408-424.
Gilligan, T.W. and Krehbiel, K. (1989), Asymmetric information and legislative rules with a heterogeneous committee, American Journal of Political Science, 33, 459-490.
Groothuis, P.A. and Miller, G. (1997), The role of social distrust in risk-benefit analysis : a study of the siting of a hazardous waste disposal facility, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 15, 241-257.
Klevorick, A., Rothschild, M. and Winship, C. (1984), Information processing and jury decision making, Journal of Public Economics, 23, 245-278.
Ladha, K. (1992), The condorcet jury theorem, free speech, and correlated votes, American Journal of Political Science,36(3), 617-634.
Letterie, W. and Swank, O. (1997), Learning and signaling by advisor selection, public choice, 92, 353-367.
Letterie, W. and Swank, O. (1998), Economic policy, model uncertainty and elections, Economics and Politics, 10(1), 85-103.
Li,H., Sherwin,R. and Wing, S. (1999), Conflicts and common interest in committees, NBER working paper No.W7158.
Lindbeck, A. and Weibull, J. (1993), A model of political equilibrium in a representative democracy, Journal of Public Economics, 51, 195-209.
Lohmann, S. (1994), Information through costly political action, American Economic Review, 84(3), 518-530.
Mitchell, D.W. (1987), Candidate behavior under mixed motives, Social Choice and Welfare, 4, 153-160.
Niskanen, W.A. (1971), Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine.
Roemer, J. (1994), The strategic role of party ideology when voters are uncertain about how economy works, American Political Science Review, 88, 327-335.
Schultz, C. (1995), The politics of persuasion when voters are rational, Scandinavian Journal of Economics , 97, 357-368.
Spector, D. (2000), Pure communication between agent with close preferences, Economics Letters, 66, 171-178.
Swank, O. (1993), Partisan view on the economy, Public Choice, 81, 137-150.
Veendorp, E. and Majeed, A. (1995), Differentiation in a two-dimensional market, Regional Science & Urban Economics, 25, 75-83.
Warnery, K. (1994), Partisanship as information, Public Choice, 80(3-4), 371-380. |