Reference: | Antràs, P. and G. Padró i Miquel (2011), “Foreign Influence and Welfare,” Journal of International Economics, 84(2), 135-148. Arnold, P. A., Clack G., and P. Malamud ed. (2004), About America: How the United States Is Governed, Virginia: Braddock Communications Inc. Becker, G. S. and G. J. Stigler (1974), “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies, 3(1), 1-18. Bertrand, J. (1883), “Théorie Mathématique de la Richesse Sociale,” Journal des Savants, 67, 499-508. Bombardini, M. and F. Trebbi (2011), “Votes or Money? Theory and Evidence from the US Congress,” Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8), 587-611. Bown, C. P., and P. Tovar (2011), “Trade Liberalization, Antidumping, and Safeguards: Evidence from India`s Tariff Reform,” Journal of Development Economics, 96(1), 115-125. Buchanan, J. M. (1972), “Fiscal Policy and Fiscal Preference,” in R. D. Tollison (ed.), Theory of Public Choice, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Damania, R., Fredriksson, P. G., and M. Mani (2004), “The Persistence of Corruption and Regulatory Compliance Failures: Theory and Evidence,” Public Choice, 121(3), 363–390. Drugov, M. (2010), “Competition in Bureaucracy and Corruption,” Journal of Development Economics, 92(2), 107-114. Friehe, T. (2008), “Correlated Payoffs in the Inspection Game: Some Theory and an Application to Corruption,” Public Choice, 137(1), 127–143. Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1994), “Protection for Sale.” American Economic Review, 84(4), 833-850. Hotelling, H. (1929), “Stability in competition,” Economic Journal, 39, 41-57. Krueger, A. O. (1974), “The Political Economy of Rent-Seeking Society,”American Economic Review, 64(3), 291-303. Laffont, J.-J. and T. N`Guessan (1999), “Competition and Corruption in an Agency Relationship,” Journal of Development Economics, 60(2), 271-295. Mookherjee, D., and I. P. L. Png (1995), “Corruptible Law Enforcers: How Should They Be Compensated,” Economic Journal, 105(428), 145–159. Mueller, D. C. (1989), Public Choice II, New York: Cambridge University Press. Niskanen, W. A. (1968), “The Peculiar Economics of Bureaucracy,” American Economic Review, 58(2), 293-305. Oi, W. Y. (1971), “A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85(1), 77-96. Posner, R. A. (1975), “The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation,” Journal of Political Economy, 83(4), 807-827. Priks, M. (2011), “Judiciaries in Corrupt Societies,” Economics of Governance, 12(1), 75-88. Priks, M. (2012), “Competition among officials and the abuse of power,” Public Choice, 150(3), 425-438. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978), Corruption: a study in political economy, New York: Academic Press. Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny (1993), “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617. Swinnen, J. F. M. and T. Vandemoortele (2011), “Trade and the Political Economy of Food Standards,” Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(2), 259-280. Tovar, P. (2011), “Lobbying Costs and Trade Policy,” Journal of International Economics, 83(2), 126-136. Tullock, G. (1965), The Politics of Bureaucracy, Washington, D. C.: Public Affairs Press. Tullock, G. (1967), “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft,” Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224-232. Tullock, G. (1980), “Efficient Rent Seeking,” in J. M. Buchanan and R. D. Tollison (ed.), Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, College Station: Texas A & M University Press. |